2009 OASDI Trustees Report

Table of Contents Previous Next Tables Figures Index


 
B. LONG-RANGE ESTIMATES
Three types of financial measures are useful in assessing the actuarial status of the Social Security trust funds under the financing approach specified in current law: (1) annual cash-flow measures, including income and cost rates, and balances; (2) trust fund ratios; and (3) summary measures like actuarial balances and unfunded obligations. The first long-range estimates presented are the series of projected annual balances (or net cash flow), which are the differences between the projected annual income rates and annual cost rates (expressed as percentages of the taxable payroll). In assessing the financial condition of the program, particular attention should be paid to the level of the annual balances at the end of the long-range period and the time at which the annual balances may change from positive to negative values.
The next measure discussed is the pattern of projected trust fund ratios. The trust fund ratio represents the proportion of a year’s projected cost that could be paid with the funds available at the beginning of the year. Particular atten­tion should be paid to the level and year of maximum trust fund ratio, to the year of exhaustion of the funds, and to the stability of the trust fund ratio in cases where the ratio remains positive at the end of the long-range period. When a program has positive trust fund ratios throughout the 75-year projec­tion period and these ratios are stable or rising at the end of the period, the program financing is said to achieve sustainable solvency.
The final measures discussed in this section summarize the total income and cost over valuation periods that extend through 75 years, and to the infinite horizon. These measures indicate whether projected income will be adequate for the period as a whole. The first such measure, actuarial balance, indicates the size of any surplus or shortfall as a percentage of the taxable payroll over the period. The second, open group unfunded obligation, indicates the size of any shortfall in present-value dollars. This section also includes a compari­son of covered workers to beneficiaries, a generational decomposition of the infinite future unfunded obligation, the test of long-range close actuarial bal­ance, and the reasons for change in the actuarial balance from the last report.
If the 75-year actuarial balance is zero (or positive), then the trust fund ratio at the end of the period will be at 100 percent (or greater), and financing for the program is considered to be adequate for the 75-year period as a whole. Financial adequacy, or solvency, for each year is determined by whether the trust fund asset level is positive throughout the year. Whether or not financial adequacy is stable in the sense that it is likely to continue for subsequent 75-year periods in succeeding reports is also important when considering the actuarial status of the program. One indication of this stability, or sustainable solvency, is the behavior of the trust fund ratio at the end of the projection period. If trust fund ratios for the last several years of the long-range period are positive and are at a constant or rising level, then it is likely that subse­quent Trustees Reports will also show projections of financial adequacy (assuming no changes in demographic and economic assumptions, or the law). The actuarial balance and the open group unfunded obligation for the infinite future provide additional measures of the financial status of the pro­gram for the very long range.
1. Annual Income Rates, Cost Rates, and Balances
Basic to the consideration of the long-range actuarial status of the trust funds are the concepts of income rate and cost rate, each of which is expressed as a percentage of taxable payroll. Other measures of the cash flow of the pro­gram are shown in Appendix F. The annual income rate is the sum of the tax contribution rate and the ratio of income from taxation of benefits to the OASDI taxable payroll for the year. The OASDI taxable payroll consists of the total earnings that are subject to OASDI taxes, with some relatively small adjustments.1
The annual cost rate is the ratio of the cost of the program to the taxable pay­roll for the year. The cost is defined to include scheduled benefit payments, administrative expenses, net transfers from the trust funds to the Railroad Retirement program under the financial-interchange provisions, and pay­ments for vocational rehabilitation services for disabled beneficiaries. For any year, the income rate minus the cost rate is referred to as the balance for the year.2
Table IV.B1 presents a comparison of the estimated annual income rates and cost rates by trust fund and alternative. Detailed long-range projections of trust fund operations, in current dollar amounts, are shown in table VI.F8.
The projections for OASI under the intermediate assumptions show the income rate rising due to the gradually increasing effect of the taxation of benefits. The projected income from the taxation of benefits, expressed as a percentage of taxable payroll, is expected to increase for two reasons. First, benefits are rising faster than payroll. Second, the benefit-taxation threshold amounts are not indexed, so that an increasing share of beneficiaries will be paying tax on their benefits. The pattern of the cost rate is much different. The cost rate rises in 2009 and 2010 due to the projected economic recession, and then comes back down through 2012 due to the recovery. From about 2012 to 2030, the cost rate rises rapidly because the retirement of the baby-boom generation will cause the number of beneficiaries to rise much faster than the labor force. After 2030, the cost rate remains fairly stable for about 30 years because the number of workers and beneficiaries are projected to rise at the same rate. Thereafter, the cost rate rises slowly, reflecting pro­jected reductions in death rates and continued relatively low birth rates. The cost rate reaches 15.35 percent of taxable payroll for 2083. By comparison, the income rate reaches 11.48 percent of taxable payroll for 2083.
Projected income rates under the low-cost and high-cost sets of assumptions are very similar to those projected for the intermediate assumptions because they are largely a reflection of the tax rates specified in the law. OASI cost rates for the low-cost and high-cost assumptions differ significantly from those projected for the intermediate assumptions. For the low-cost assump­tions, the cost rate decreases from 2010 through 2013, then rises, until it peaks in 2033 at a level of 13.01 percent of payroll. The cost rate then gener­ally declines gradually, reaching a level of 10.92 percent of payroll for 2083 (at which point the income rate reaches 11.22 percent). For the high-cost assumptions, the cost rate rises from 2011 through the end of the 75-year period. It rises at a relatively fast pace between 2011 and 2030 because of the aging of the baby-boom generation. Subsequently, the projected cost rate continues rising and reaches 22.41 percent of payroll for 2083 (at which point the income rate reaches 11.88 percent).
The pattern of the projected OASI annual balance is important in the analysis of the financial condition of the program. Under the intermediate assump­tions, the annual balance is positive for 8 years (through 2016) and is nega­tive thereafter. This annual deficit rises rapidly, reaching 2 percent of taxable payroll by 2024, and continues rising generally thereafter, to a level of 3.87 percent of taxable payroll for 2083.
Under the low-cost assumptions, the projected OASI annual balance is posi­tive for 11 years (through 2019) and then becomes negative, with the annual deficit peaking at 1.74 percent of taxable payroll for 2033. Then, the annual deficit declines until 2065, when the OASI annual balance becomes positive, reaching a surplus of 0.30 percent of payroll in 2083. Under the high-cost assumptions, in contrast, the OASI balance is projected to be positive for only 5 years (through 2013) and to be negative thereafter, with a deficit of 2.19 percent for 2020, 6.30 percent for 2050, and 10.53 percent of payroll for 2083.
 
Table IV.B1.—Annual Income Rates, Cost Rates, and Balances,
Calendar Years 1990-2085 [As a percentage of taxable payroll]
Income
rate a
Income
rate a
First year balance becomes
negative and remains negative
through 2085
First year balance becomes
negative and remains negative
through
First year balance becomes
negative and remains negative
through 2085

a
Historical income rates are modified to include adjustments to the lump-sum payments received in 1983 from the General Fund of the Treasury for the cost of noncontributory wage credits for military service in 1940-56.

b
Between -0.005 and 0.005 percent of taxable payroll.

c
The annual balance is projected to be negative for a temporary period, returning to positive levels before the end of the projection period.

Notes:
1. The income rate excludes interest income and certain transfers from the General Fund of the Treasury.
2. Some historical values are subject to change due to revisions of taxable payroll.
3. Totals do not necessarily equal the sums of rounded components.
Under the intermediate assumptions, the cost rate for DI fluctuates between 2.15 and 2.30 percent of taxable payroll from 2009 to 2034, generally increasing thereafter to 2.34 percent for 2083. The income rate increases only very slightly from 1.84 percent of taxable payroll for 2009 to 1.87 percent for 2083. The annual deficit is about 0.34 percent in 2009 and reaches 0.47 percent for 2083.
Under the low-cost assumptions, the DI cost rate peaks at 2.15 percent of payroll for 2010, then generally declines slowly thereafter, reaching 1.57 percent for 2083. The annual balance is negative for the first 7 years and is positive throughout the remainder of the long-range period. For the high-cost assumptions, DI cost rises much more, reaching 3.29 percent for 2083. The annual deficit is about 0.39 percent in 2009 and reaches 1.39 percent for 2083.
Figure IV.B1 shows in graphical form the patterns of the OASI and DI annual income rates and cost rates. The income rates shown here are only for alternative II in order to simplify the graphical presentation because, as shown in table IV.B1, the variation in the income rates by alternative is very small. Income rates increase generally, but at a slow rate for each of the alter­natives over the long-range period. Both increases in the income rate and variation among the alternatives result from the relatively small component of income from taxation of benefits. Increases in income from taxation of benefits reflect increases in the total amount of benefits paid and the fact that an increasing share of individual benefits will be subject to taxation because benefit taxation threshold amounts are not indexed.
The patterns of the annual balances for OASI and DI can be inferred from figure IV.B1. For each alternative, the magnitude of each of the positive bal­ances, as a percentage of taxable payroll, is represented by the distance between the appropriate cost-rate curve and the income-rate curve above it. The magnitude of each of the deficits is represented by the distance between the appropriate cost-rate curve and the income-rate curve below it.
In the future, the cost of OASI, DI and the combined OASDI programs as a percentage of taxable payroll will not necessarily be within the range encom­passed by alternatives I and III. Nonetheless, because alternatives I and III define a reasonably wide range of demographic and economic conditions, the resulting estimates delineate a reasonable range for consideration of potential future program costs.
 
Figure IV.B1.—Long-Range OASI and DI Annual Income Rates and Cost Rates
[As a percentage of taxable payroll]
Thus far in this section, the cost and income of the OASDI program have been discussed with reference to their size relative to taxable payroll, which is the base from which most of the income is derived for the OASDI pro­gram. Also of interest are estimates of income and cost expressed as shares of gross domestic product (GDP), the value of goods and services produced during the year in the United States. Under alternative II, OASDI cost gener­ally rises from about 4.8 percent of GDP currently to 6.1 percent in 2030, and then peaks at almost 6.2 percent in 2034. Thereafter, OASDI cost as a percent of GDP is projected to decline, reaching a level around 5.8 percent for the period 2050 through 2083. Full estimates of income and cost are pre­sented on this basis in Appendix VI.F.2 beginning on page 182.
2. Comparison of Workers to Beneficiaries
The estimated OASDI cost rate is expected to rise rapidly between 2012 and 2030 primarily because the number of beneficiaries is expected to rise sub­stantially more rapidly than the number of covered workers as the baby-boom generation retires. This occurs largely because of the swings in fertility rates over time. Because the baby-boom generation had low fertility rates rel­ative to their parents, and those low fertility rates are expected to persist, the ratio of beneficiaries to workers is expected to rise rapidly, reaching a perma­nently higher level after the baby-boom generation retires. After 2030, the ratio of beneficiaries to workers rises slowly due to increasing longevity. A comparison of the numbers of covered workers and beneficiaries is shown in table IV.B2.
 
Covered
workers a
(in thousands)
Beneficiaries b (in thousands)
Covered
workers per
OASDI
beneficiary
OASDI beneficiaries
per 100
covered
workers

a
Workers who are paid at some time during the year for employment on which OASDI taxes are due.

b
Beneficiaries with monthly benefits in current-payment status as of June 30.

Notes:
1. The number of beneficiaries does not include uninsured individuals who receive benefits under Section 228 of the Social Security Act. Costs are reimbursed from the General Fund of the Treasury for most of these individuals.
2. Historical covered worker data are subject to revision.
3. Totals do not necessarily equal the sums of rounded components.
The impact of the demographic shifts under the three alternatives on the OASDI cost rates is readily seen by considering the projected number of OASDI beneficiaries per 100 covered workers. As compared to the 2008 level of 31 beneficiaries per 100 covered workers, this ratio is estimated to rise to 46 by 2030 and 48 by 2035 under intermediate assumptions, as the growth in beneficiaries greatly exceeds the growth in workers. By 2085, this ratio rises significantly under all three alternatives, reaching 39 under the low-cost assumptions, 52 under the intermediate assumptions, and 69 under the high-cost assumptions. The significance of these numbers can be seen by comparing figure IV.B1 to figure IV.B2.
For each alternative, the shape of the curve in figure IV.B2, which shows beneficiaries per 100 covered workers, is strikingly similar to that of the cor­responding cost-rate curve in figure IV.B1, thereby emphasizing the extent to which the cost of the OASDI program as a percentage of taxable payroll is determined by the age distribution of the population. Because the cost rate is basically the product of the number of beneficiaries and their average bene­fit, divided by the product of the number of covered workers and their aver­age taxable earnings (and because average benefits rise at about the same rate as average earnings), it is to be expected that the pattern of the annual cost rates is similar to that of the annual ratios of beneficiaries to workers.
 
Table IV.B2 also shows the number of covered workers per OASDI benefi­ciary, which was about 3.2 in 2008. This ratio declines under all three alter­natives because it is the inverse of the ratio of beneficiaries to workers.
3. Trust Fund Ratios
Trust fund ratios are useful indicators of the adequacy of the financial resources of the Social Security program at any point in time. For any year in which the projected trust fund ratio is positive (i.e., the trust fund holds assets at the beginning of the year), but is not positive for the following year, the trust fund is projected to become exhausted during the year. Under present law, the OASI and DI Trust Funds do not have the authority to bor­row. Therefore, exhaustion of the assets in either fund during a year would mean there are no longer sufficient assets in the fund to cover the full amount of benefits scheduled for the year under present law.
The trust fund ratio also serves an additional important purpose in assessing the actuarial status of the program. When the financing is adequate for the timely payment of full benefits throughout the long-range period, the stabil­ity of the trust fund ratio toward the end of the period indicates the likelihood that this projected adequacy will continue for subsequent Trustees Reports. If the trust fund ratio toward the end of the period is level (or increasing), then projected adequacy for the long-range period is likely to continue for subse­quent reports. Under these conditions, the program financing is said to achieve sustainable solvency.
Table IV.B3 shows, by alternative, the estimated trust fund ratios (without regard to advance tax transfers that would be effected after the end of the 10‑year, short-range period) for the separate and combined OASI and DI Trust Funds. Also shown in this table is the year in which a fund is estimated to become exhausted, reflecting the effect of the provision for advance tax transfers.
Based on the intermediate assumptions, the OASI trust fund ratio rises from 392 percent at the beginning of 2009, reaching a peak of 422 percent at the beginning of 2012. This increase in the OASI trust fund ratio results from the fact that the annual income rate exceeds the annual cost rate for several years (see table IV.B1). Thereafter, the OASI trust fund ratio declines steadily, with the OASI Trust Fund becoming exhausted in 2039. The DI trust fund ratio has been declining steadily since 2003, and is estimated to continue to decline from 179 percent at the beginning of 2009 until the trust fund becomes exhausted in 2020.
The trust fund ratio for the combined OASI and DI Trust Funds under the intermediate assumptions rises from 354 percent for 2009 to a peak of 369 percent at the beginning of 2012. Thereafter, the ratio declines, with the combined funds becoming exhausted in 2037. In last year’s report, the peak trust fund ratio for the combined funds was estimated to be 395 percent for 2014 and the year of exhaustion was estimated to be 2041.
The trust fund ratio for the OASDI program under the intermediate assump­tions first declines in 2013. This occurs because the increase in trust fund assets during 2012, which reflects interest income and a small excess of non­interest income over cost, occurs at a slower rate than does the increase in the annual cost of the program between 2012 and 2013. After 2012, the dollar amount of assets is projected to continue to rise through the beginning of 2024 because interest income more than offsets the shortfall in noninterest income.
Beginning in 2016, the OASDI program under the intermediate assumptions is projected to experience increasingly large cash-flow shortfalls that will require the trust funds to redeem special public-debt obligations of the Gen­eral Fund of the Treasury. This will differ from the experience of recent years when the trust funds have been net lenders to the General Fund of the Trea­sury. The change in the cash flow between the trust funds and the general fund is expected to have important public policy and economic implications that go well beyond the operation of the OASDI program itself.
Based on the low-cost assumptions, the trust fund ratio for the DI program increases from 2014 through the end of the long-range projection period, reaching the extremely high level of 1,683 percent for 2084. At the end of the long-range period, the DI trust fund ratio is rising by 33 percentage points per year. For the OASI program, the trust fund ratio rises to a peak of 451 percent for 2017, drops to a low of 261 percent for 2052, and rises there­after to a level of 389 percent for 2084. At the end of the period, the OASI trust fund ratio is rising by 6 percentage points per year. For the OASDI pro­gram, the trust fund ratio peaks at 408 percent for 2018, falls to 301 percent for 2044, and increases thereafter, reaching 552 percent for 2084. Because the trust fund ratios are large and increasing at the end of the long-range period, subsequent Trustees Reports are likely to contain projections of ade­quate long-range financing of the OASI, the DI, and the combined OASI and DI programs under the low-cost assumptions. Thus, under the low-cost assumptions, each program would achieve sustainable solvency.
In contrast, under the high-cost assumptions, the OASI trust fund ratio is estimated to peak at 413 percent for 2012, thereafter declining to fund exhaustion by the end of 2031. The DI trust fund ratio is estimated to decline from 176 percent for 2009 to fund exhaustion by the end of 2016. The com­bined OASDI trust fund ratio is estimated to rise to a peak of 360 percent for 2011, declining thereafter to fund exhaustion by the end of 2029.
Thus, because large ultimate cost rates are projected under all but the low-cost assumptions, it is likely that income will eventually need to be increased, and/or program costs will need to be reduced in order to prevent the trust funds from becoming exhausted.
Even under the high-cost assumptions, however, the combined OASI and DI funds on hand plus their estimated future income would be able to cover their combined cost for 20 years into the future (until 2029). Under the intermedi­ate assumptions the combined starting funds plus estimated future income would be able to cover cost for about 28 years into the future (until 2037). The program would be able to cover cost for the foreseeable future under the more optimistic low-cost assumptions. In the 2008 report, the combined trust funds were projected to become exhausted in 2031 under the high-cost assumptions and in 2041 under the intermediate assumptions.
.